Exercise 4.2

Variation of the PAC Model

⬅ Return

Problem

This exercise aims to establish whether formulating portfolio adjustment costs as a function of the deviation of the household’s debt position from an exogenous reference point, \(d_t - \bar{d}\), or as a function of the change in its debt position, \(d_t - d_{t-1}\), has consequences for the stationarity of the model.

Consider a small open economy populated by a large number of infinitely-lived households with preferences described by the utility function

\[ E_0 \sum_{t=0}^\infty \beta^t \ln c_t, \]

where \(\beta \in (0,1)\) denotes the subjective discount factor, and \(c_t\) denotes consumption in period \(t\). Each period, households receive an exogenous and stochastic endowment, \(y_t\), and can borrow from (or lend to) international financial markets at the gross interest rate \(1 + r\). Let \(d_t\) denote the stock of foreign debt held by households at the end of period \(t\). Households are subject to a portfolio adjustment cost of the form \(\frac{\phi}{2} (d_t - d_{t-1})^2\), where \(\phi\) is a positive constant. Assume that \(\beta(1 + r) = 1\).

  1. State the household’s period-by-period budget constraint.

  2. State the household’s utility maximization problem.

  3. Write the Lagrangian of the household’s problem.

  4. Define a competitive equilibrium of this economy.

  5. Suppose the endowment is nonstochastic and constant, \(y_t = y\), for all \(t\). Characterize the deterministic steady state. Does it exist? Is it unique? Hint: Consult appendix 4.14.2.

  6. Consider now a temporary endowment shock. Suppose \(y_0 > y\) and \(y_t = y\) for all \(t > 0\) deterministically. Suppose that prior to period 0 the economy was in a deterministic steady state with \(d_{-1} = d^*\). Is the economy stationary, that is, is \(d_t\) expected to return to \(d^*\)? Provide intuition.

Answer

1.

\[ y_t + (1 + r) b_{t-1} = c_t + b_t + \frac{\phi}{2}(b_t - b_{t-1})^2 \]

2.

\[ \max_{c_t, b_t} E_0 \sum_{t=0}^\infty \ln c_t \]

subject to

\[ y_t + (1 + r)b_{t-1} = c_t + b_t + \frac{\phi}{2}(b_t - b_{t-1})^2 \]

and some no-Ponzi game constraint taking as given the initial condition \(b_{-1}\), the exogenous process \(\{y_t\}\), the interest rate \(r\).

3.

\[ \mathcal{L} = E_0 \sum_{t=0}^\infty \beta^t \left\{ \ln c_t + \lambda_t \left[ y_t + (1 + r)b_{t-1} - c_t - b_t - \frac{\phi}{2}(b_t - b_{t-1})^2 \right] \right\} \]

where \(\lambda_t\) denote the Lagrange multiplier on the household’s period-by-period budget constraint.

4.

A competitive equilibrium is a set of contingent plans \(\{c_t, b_t, \lambda_t\}\) satisfying:

\[ \frac{1}{c_t} = \lambda_t \]

\[ \lambda_t (1 + \phi(b_t - b_{t-1})) = \beta E_t \lambda_{t+1}(1 + r + \phi(b_{t+1} - b_t)) \]

\[ y_t + (1 + r)b_{t-1} = c_t + b_t + \frac{\phi}{2}(b_t - b_{t-1})^2 \]

and some no Ponzi game constraint, for given exogenous processes, \(y_t\), and given initial conditions \(b_{-1}\).

5.

In the deterministic steady state all endogenous variables are by definition forever constant. Thus a deterministic steady state is a triple \(\{c, \lambda, b\}\) that solves:

\[ \frac{1}{c} = \lambda \]

\[ \lambda = \lambda \beta(1 + r) \]

\[ y + rb = c \]

Notice that the Euler equation does not impose a restriction, it just says \(1 = 1\). Thus there exist a continuum of steady state equilibria. In fact any \(b\) such that \(c = y + rb > 0\) is a deterministic steady state. We do not need to check the no Ponzi restriction. It is satisfied because \(b\) is constant and because \(r > 0\).

6.

Consider first the economy from period \(t \geq 1\). In that case there is no uncertainty and one equilibrium is to set:

\[ b_t = b_0 \quad \forall t \geq 1 \]

\[ c_t = y + rb_0 \]

\[ \lambda = \frac{1}{y + rb_0} \]

Now consider the economy in period \(t = 0\):

\[ y_0 + (1 + r)b_{-1} = c_0 + b_0 + \frac{\phi}{2}(b_0 - b_{-1})^2 \]

and use the Euler equation:

\[ \frac{1}{c_0}(1 + \phi(b_0 - b_{-1})) = \frac{1}{c_1}(1 + r + \phi(b_1 - b_0)) \]

We already know that \(b_1 = b_0\) so this expression becomes:

\[ \frac{1}{c_0}(1 + \phi(b_0 - b_{-1})) = \frac{1}{c_1} \]

where we used \(\beta(1 + r) = 1\) now use \(c_1 = y + rb_0\) and rearrange:

\[ c_0 = (1 + \phi(b_0 - b_{-1}))(y + rb_0) \]

Now use the sequential budget constraint for \(t = 0\):

\[ c_0 + b_0 + \frac{\phi}{2}(b_0 - b_{-1})^2 = y_0 + (1 + r)b_{-1} \]

Now for \(b_t \to b_{-1}\), notice that \(\lim_{t \to \infty} b_t = b_0\). Thus let’s try \(b_0 = b_{-1}\). Then the above expression becomes:

\[ c_0 + b_{-1} = y_0 + (1 + r)b_{-1} \]

and replace \(c_0\) with the expression from the Euler equation

\[ c_0 = (1 + \phi(b_0 - b_{-1}))(y + rb_0) = y + rb_{-1} \]

to get:

\[ y + rb_{-1} + b_{-1} = y_0 + (1 + r)b_{-1} \]

This holds only if \(y_0 = y\), which can never be the case. Thus the model is not stationary.