Exercise 4.12

GHH Preferences and No Capital

⬅ Return

Problem

Consider a small open economy populated by an infinite number of identical households with preferences of the form

\[ (1-\sigma)^{-1}\sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t \left(c_t-\frac{h_t^{\omega}}{\omega} \right)^{1-\sigma}, \]

where \(c_t\) denotes consumption of a perishable good in period \(t\), \(h_t\) denotes labor effort in period \(t\), and \(\beta\in(0,1)\), \(\sigma>1\), and \(\omega>1\) are parameters. Each household operates a technology that produces consumption goods according to the relationship

\[ y_t = h_t^{\alpha}, \]

where \(y_t\) denotes output, and \(\alpha\in(0,1)\) is a parameter. The household can borrow or lend in international financial markets at the interest rate \(r_t = r^*+p(\tilde{d}_t)\), where \(r^*\) denotes the world interest rate and satisfies \(\beta(1+r^*)=1\). The function \(p(\tilde{d}_t)\) is a country interest-rate premium in period \(t\), satisfying \(p(0)=0\), and \(p(x)\neq0\) for \(x\neq0\), where \(\tilde{d}_t\) denotes the cross-sectional average debt holdings in period \(t\) and is taken as given by the individual household. Let \(d_t\) denote the household’s debt holdings in period \(t\) maturing in \(t+1\). Households cannot play Ponzi games.

  1. Write down the household’s optimization problem.

  2. Derive the first-order conditions associated with the household’s optimization problem.

  3. Display the complete set of equilibrium conditions.

  4. Derive the steady state of the economy. In particular, compute the steady-state values of consumption, hours, output, the trade balance, the current account, and external debt, denoted, respectively, \(c\), \(h\), \(y\), \(tb\), \(ca\), and \(d\).

  5. Derive analytically a first-order approximation to the equilibrium conditions. Express it as a first-order difference equation in the vector \([\hat{d}_{t-1} \,\, \hat{c}_t]'\), where \(\hat{d}_{t-1}\equiv d_{t-1}-d\), and \(\hat{c}_t\equiv \ln(c_t/c)\).

  6. Derive conditions under which the perfect-foresight equilibrium is locally unique.

Answer

  1. The household chooses \(\{c_t, h_t, d_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) to maximize \[ \sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t \frac{\left(c_t - \frac{h_t^{\omega}}{\omega} \right)^{1 - \sigma}}{1 - \sigma} \] subject to the sequence of budget constraints: \[ c_t + d_t = h_t^{\alpha} + (1 + r_{t-1}) d_{t-1}, \] taking \(r_t\) and \(d_{-1}\) as given and satisfying the no-Ponzi condition.

  2. The first-order conditions are:

  • With respect to \(c_t\): \[ \left(c_t - \frac{h_t^{\omega}}{\omega}\right)^{-\sigma} = \lambda_t \]
  • With respect to \(h_t\): \[ \left(c_t - \frac{h_t^{\omega}}{\omega}\right)^{-\sigma} h_t^{\omega - 1} = \lambda_t \alpha h_t^{\alpha - 1} \]
  • With respect to \(d_t\): \[ \lambda_t = \beta (1 + r_t) \lambda_{t+1} \]
  1. The complete set of equilibrium conditions includes:
  • Intra-temporal optimality: \[ \left(c_t - \frac{h_t^{\omega}}{\omega}\right)^{-\sigma} h_t^{\omega - 1} = \lambda_t \alpha h_t^{\alpha - 1} \]
  • Inter-temporal Euler equation: \[ \lambda_t = \beta (1 + r_t) \lambda_{t+1} \]
  • Budget constraint: \[ c_t + d_t = h_t^{\alpha} + (1 + r_{t-1}) d_{t-1} \]
  • Interest rate function: \[ r_t = r^* + p(d_t) \]
  • No-Ponzi condition: \[ \lim_{T \to \infty} \frac{d_T}{\prod_{s=0}^{T-1} (1 + r_s)} = 0 \]
  1. In steady state, \(r = r^*\), \(d = 0\), and \(h\) satisfies: \[ h = \bar{h} = \alpha^{\frac{1}{\omega - \alpha}} \] Then, \[ c = y = \bar{h}^{\alpha}, \quad tb = ca = d = 0 \]

  2. Let \(\hat{d}_{t-1} = d_{t-1}\) and \(\hat{c}_t = \ln(c_t / c)\). Then the linearized system becomes: \[ \hat{d}_t = \beta^{-1} \hat{d}_{t-1} + c \hat{c}_t \] \[ \hat{c}_{t+1} = \frac{p'(0)}{\sigma } \cdot \frac{\omega - \alpha}{\omega}\hat{d}_{t-1} +\left(1+ c \cdot \frac{\beta p'(0)}{\sigma}\cdot\frac{\omega - \alpha}{\omega}\right) \hat{c}_t \] which can be written in matrix form: \[ \begin{bmatrix} \hat{d}_{t} \\ \hat{c}_{t+1} \end{bmatrix} = \begin{bmatrix} \beta^{-1} & c \\ \frac{p'(0)}{\sigma } \cdot \frac{\omega - \alpha}{\omega} & 1+ c\beta \cdot \frac{p'(0)}{\sigma} \cdot \frac{\omega - \alpha}{\omega} \end{bmatrix} \begin{bmatrix} \hat{d}_{t-1} \\ \hat{c}_t \end{bmatrix} \]

  3. For local uniqueness, the system must have one eigenvalue inside and one outside the unit circle. This requires:

  • \(p'(0) > 0\)
  • \(\det(M) = \beta^{-1} > 1\)
  • \(\operatorname{tr}(M) = \beta^{-1} + 1 + c\beta X > 2\) where \(X = \frac{p'(0)}{\sigma} \cdot \frac{\omega - \alpha}{\omega} > 0\)

This ensures a saddle-path stable equilibrium with a unique perfect foresight path.