Exercise 2.2
An Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply
Problem
Consider a small open economy populated by a large number of households with preferences described by the utility function
\[ E_0 \sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t U(c_t, h_t), \]
where \(U\) is a period utility function given by
\[ U(c, h) = -\frac{1}{2} \left[ (c - \bar{c})^2 + h^2 \right], \]
where \(\bar{c} > 0\) is a satiation point. The household’s budget constraint is given by
\[ d_t = (1 + r) d_{t-1} + c_t - y_t, \]
where \(d_t\) denotes real debt acquired in period \(t\) and due in period \(t+1\), and \(r > 0\) denotes the world interest rate. To avoid inessential dynamics, we impose
\[ \beta(1 + r) = 1. \]
The variable \(y_t\) denotes output, which is assumed to be produced by the linear technology
\[ y_t = A h_t. \]
Households are also subject to the no-Ponzi-game constraint
\[ \lim_{j \to \infty} E_t \left[ \frac{d_{t+j}}{(1 + r)^j} \right] \leq 0. \]
- Compute the equilibrium laws of motion of consumption, debt, the trade balance, and the current account.
- Assume that in period 0, unexpectedly, the productivity parameter \(A\) increases permanently to \(A' > A\). Establish the effect of this shock on output, consumption, the trade balance, the current account, and the stock of debt.
Answer
1.
Household solves:
\[ \max E_0 \sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t \left[ -\frac{1}{2} \left( (\bar{c} - c_t)^2 + h_t^2 \right) \right] \]
subject to:
\[ c_t + (1 + r) d_{t-1} = y_t + d_t \]
\[ y_t = A h_t \]
\[ \lim_{j \to \infty} E_t \left[ \frac{d_{t+j}}{(1 + r)^j} \right] \leq 0 \]
Lagrangian of this problem can be written as:
\[ \mathcal{L} = E_0 \sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t \left[ -\frac{1}{2} \left( (\bar{c} - c_t)^2 + h_t^2 \right) - \lambda_t (c_t + (1 + r)d_{t-1} - A h_t - d_t) \right] \]
First order conditions:
\[ (\bar{c} - c_t) - \lambda_t = 0 \]
\[ - h_t + \lambda_t A = 0 \]
\[ \lambda_t = \beta (1 + r) E_t [\lambda_{t+1}] \]
This yields Euler Equation and optimal labor supply condition:
\[ \bar{c} - c_t = \beta(1 + r) E_t [\bar{c} - c_{t+1}] \]
\[ h_t = A (c_t - \bar{c}) \]
Recall that \((1 + r)\beta = 1\), then Euler Equation becomes:
\[ c_t = E_t [c_{t+1}] \]
\[ h_t = A (\bar{c} - c_t) \]
Intertemporal budget constraint is given by:
\[ (1 + r) d_{t-1} = \sum_{j=0}^{\infty} \frac{E_t (y_{t+j} - c_{t+j})}{(1 + r)^j} \]
Note that:
\[ E_t(y_{t+j} - c_{t+j}) = A^2 \bar{c} - E_t(A^2 c_{t+j}) - E_t(c_{t+j}) = A^2 \bar{c} - (A^2 + 1) c_t \]
Then the intertemporal budget constraint becomes:
\[ (1 + r) d_{t-1} = \frac{1 + r}{r} \left[ A^2 \bar{c} - (A^2 + 1) c_t \right] \]
Solve for \(c_t\):
\[ c_t = \frac{1}{A^2 + 1} \left[ A^2 \bar{c} - r d_{t-1} \right] \]
From the optimality condition for labor and the budget constraint:
\[ h_t = \frac{A}{A^2 + 1} \left[ \bar{c} + r d_{t-1} \right] \]
\[ tb_t = y_t - c_t = r d_{t-1} \]
\[ ca_t = tb_t - r d_{t-1} = 0 \]
2.
Recall that:
\[ c_t = \frac{1}{A^2 + 1} (A^2 \bar{c} - r d_{t-1}) \]
\[ y_t = A h_t = \frac{A^2}{A^2 + 1} (\bar{c} + r d_{t-1}) \]
\[ tb_t = y_t - c_t = r d_{t-1} \]
\[ ca_t = tb_t - r d_{t-1} = 0 \]
Therefore, consumption will increase once and for all at period \(t = 0\), output will also increase, but trade balance and current account will not change.