Exercise 2.2

An Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply

⬅ Return

Problem

Consider a small open economy populated by a large number of households with preferences described by the utility function

\[ E_0 \sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t U(c_t, h_t), \]

where \(U\) is a period utility function given by

\[ U(c, h) = -\frac{1}{2} \left[ (c - \bar{c})^2 + h^2 \right], \]

where \(\bar{c} > 0\) is a satiation point. The household’s budget constraint is given by

\[ d_t = (1 + r) d_{t-1} + c_t - y_t, \]

where \(d_t\) denotes real debt acquired in period \(t\) and due in period \(t+1\), and \(r > 0\) denotes the world interest rate. To avoid inessential dynamics, we impose

\[ \beta(1 + r) = 1. \]

The variable \(y_t\) denotes output, which is assumed to be produced by the linear technology

\[ y_t = A h_t. \]

Households are also subject to the no-Ponzi-game constraint

\[ \lim_{j \to \infty} E_t \left[ \frac{d_{t+j}}{(1 + r)^j} \right] \leq 0. \]

  1. Compute the equilibrium laws of motion of consumption, debt, the trade balance, and the current account.
  2. Assume that in period 0, unexpectedly, the productivity parameter \(A\) increases permanently to \(A' > A\). Establish the effect of this shock on output, consumption, the trade balance, the current account, and the stock of debt.

Answer

1.

Household solves:

\[ \max E_0 \sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t \left[ -\frac{1}{2} \left( (\bar{c} - c_t)^2 + h_t^2 \right) \right] \]

subject to:

\[ c_t + (1 + r) d_{t-1} = y_t + d_t \]

\[ y_t = A h_t \]

\[ \lim_{j \to \infty} E_t \left[ \frac{d_{t+j}}{(1 + r)^j} \right] \leq 0 \]

Lagrangian of this problem can be written as:

\[ \mathcal{L} = E_0 \sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t \left[ -\frac{1}{2} \left( (\bar{c} - c_t)^2 + h_t^2 \right) - \lambda_t (c_t + (1 + r)d_{t-1} - A h_t - d_t) \right] \]

First order conditions:

\[ (\bar{c} - c_t) - \lambda_t = 0 \]

\[ - h_t + \lambda_t A = 0 \]

\[ \lambda_t = \beta (1 + r) E_t [\lambda_{t+1}] \]

This yields Euler Equation and optimal labor supply condition:

\[ \bar{c} - c_t = \beta(1 + r) E_t [\bar{c} - c_{t+1}] \]

\[ h_t = A (c_t - \bar{c}) \]

Recall that \((1 + r)\beta = 1\), then Euler Equation becomes:

\[ c_t = E_t [c_{t+1}] \]

\[ h_t = A (\bar{c} - c_t) \]

Intertemporal budget constraint is given by:

\[ (1 + r) d_{t-1} = \sum_{j=0}^{\infty} \frac{E_t (y_{t+j} - c_{t+j})}{(1 + r)^j} \]

Note that:

\[ E_t(y_{t+j} - c_{t+j}) = A^2 \bar{c} - E_t(A^2 c_{t+j}) - E_t(c_{t+j}) = A^2 \bar{c} - (A^2 + 1) c_t \]

Then the intertemporal budget constraint becomes:

\[ (1 + r) d_{t-1} = \frac{1 + r}{r} \left[ A^2 \bar{c} - (A^2 + 1) c_t \right] \]

Solve for \(c_t\):

\[ c_t = \frac{1}{A^2 + 1} \left[ A^2 \bar{c} - r d_{t-1} \right] \]

From the optimality condition for labor and the budget constraint:

\[ h_t = \frac{A}{A^2 + 1} \left[ \bar{c} + r d_{t-1} \right] \]

\[ tb_t = y_t - c_t = r d_{t-1} \]

\[ ca_t = tb_t - r d_{t-1} = 0 \]

2.

Recall that:

\[ c_t = \frac{1}{A^2 + 1} (A^2 \bar{c} - r d_{t-1}) \]

\[ y_t = A h_t = \frac{A^2}{A^2 + 1} (\bar{c} + r d_{t-1}) \]

\[ tb_t = y_t - c_t = r d_{t-1} \]

\[ ca_t = tb_t - r d_{t-1} = 0 \]

Therefore, consumption will increase once and for all at period \(t = 0\), output will also increase, but trade balance and current account will not change.